Home > Insert Presentation title here

Insert Presentation title here


Summer School on 
Matching Problems,  
Markets and Mechanisms
 

David Manlove


1  

Nobel prize in Economic Sciences, 2012


Outline 
 

      1. The Hospitals / Residents problem 
        and its variants
      1. The House Allocation problem 
         
         
      1. Kidney exchange 
         
         
         
 

2


Tutorial 1 
 

The Hospitals / Residents problem 
and its variants
 
 
 
 

with applications to Junior Doctor Allocation 

3


Primer: computational complexity (1) 

4  

      • Given two functions f and g, we say f(n)=O(g(n)) if there are positive constants c and N such that f(n) c.g(n) for all nN
      • An algorithm for a problem has time complexity O(g(n)) if its running time f satisfies f(n)=O(g(n)) where n is the input size
      • An algorithm runs in polynomial time if its time complexity is O(nc) for some constant c, where n is the input size
      • A decision problem is a problem whose solution is yes or no for any input
      • A decision problem belongs to the class P if it has a polynomial-time algorithm
      • If a decision problem is NP-complete it has no polynomial-time algorithm unless P=NP

Primer: computational complexity (2) 

5  

      • An optimisation problem is a problem that involves maximising or minimising (subject to a suitable measure) over a set of feasible solutions for a given instance
        • e.g., colour a graph using as few colours as possible
      • If an optimisation problem is NP-hard it has no polynomial-time algorithm unless P=NP
      • An approximation algorithm A for an optimisation problem is a polynomial-time algorithm that produces a feasible solution A(I) for any instance I
      • A has performance guarantee c, for some c>1 if
        • |A(I)| c.opt(I) for any instance I (in the case of a minimisation problem)
        • |A(I)| (1/c).opt(I) for any instance I (in the case of a maximisation problem)

where

opt(I)

is the measure of an optimal solution


Centralised matching schemes 

6  

      • Intending junior doctors must undergo training in hospitals
      • Applicants rank hospitals in order of preference
      • Hospitals do likewise with their applicants
      • Centralised matching schemes (clearinghouses) produce a matching in several countries
        • US (National Resident Matching Program)
        • Canada (Canadian Resident Matching Service)
        • Japan (Japan Residency Matching Program)
        • Scotland (Scottish Foundation Allocation Scheme)
          • typically 700-750 applicants and 50 hospitals
      • Stability is the key property of a matching
        • [Roth, 1984]

 


Tutorial Outline 

7  

1.1: Classical Hospitals / Residents problem 

1.2: Hospitals / Residents problem with Ties 

1.3: Hospitals / Residents problem with Couples 

1.4: “Almost stable” matchings 

1.5: Social Stability


Tutorial Outline 

8  

1.1: Classical Hospitals / Residents problem 

1.2: Hospitals / Residents problem with Ties 

1.3: Hospitals / Residents problem with Couples 

1.4: “Almost stable” matchings 

1.5: Social Stability


Hospitals / Residents problem (HR) 

9  

      • Underlying theoretical model: Hospitals / Residents problem (HR)
      • We have n1 residents r1, r2, , rn1 and n2 hospitals h1, h2, , hn2
      • Each hospital has a capacity
      • Residents rank hospitals in order of preference, hospitals do likewise
      • r finds h acceptable if h is on r’s preference list, and unacceptable otherwise (and vice versa)
      • A matching M is a set of resident-hospital pairs such that:
  1. (r,h)M r, h find each other acceptable
  • No resident appears in more than one pair
  • No hospital appears in more pairs than its capacity

HR: example instance 

10  

r1: h2 h1

r2: h1 h2

                 

Each hospital has capacity

2

r3: h1 h3

r4: h2 h3

 

h1: r1 r3 r2 r5 r6

r5: h2 h1

 

h2: r2 r6 r1 r4 r5

r6: h1 h2

 

h3: r4 r3 

Resident preferences Hospital preferences


HR: example matching 

11  

r1: h2

h1

r2: h1

h2

                 

Each hospital has capacity

2

r3: h1

h3

r4: h2 h3

 

h1:

 

r1

 

r3 r2 r5

r6

r5:

h2

 

h1

 

h2:

 

r2

 

r6 r1 r4

r5

r6:

h1

 

h2

 

h3: r4

r3 

Resident preferences Hospital preferences 

M = {(r1, h1), (r2, h2), (r3, h3), (r5, h2), (r6, h1)}

(size

5

)

 


HR: stability 

12  

      • Matching M is stable if M admits no blocking pair
    • (r,h) is a blocking pair of matching M if: 
 
 

1.

r

,

h

find each other acceptable 

      

and 

2. either

 

r

is unmatched in

M

      

or

r

prefers

h

to his/her assigned hospital in

M 

      

and 

3. either

h

is undersubscribed in

M

      

or

 

h

prefers

r

to its worst resident assigned in

M


HR: blocking pair (1) 

13  

r1: h2

h1

r2: h1

h2

                 

Each hospital has capacity

2

r3: h1

h3

r4: h2 h3

 

h1:

 

r1

 

r3 r2 r5

r6

r5:

h2

 

h1

 

h2:

 

r2

 

r6 r1 r4

r5

r6:

h1

 

h2

 

h3: r4

r3 

Resident preferences Hospital preferences 

M = {(r1, h1), (r2, h2), (r3, h3), (r5, h2), (r6, h1)}

(size

5


(r2, h1)

is a blocking pair of

M


HR: blocking pair (2) 

14  

r1: h2

h1

r2: h1

h2

                 

Each hospital has capacity

2

r3: h1

h3

r4: h2 h3

 

h1:

 

r1

 

r3 r2 r5

r6

r5:

h2

 

h1

 

h2:

 

r2

 

r6 r1 r4

r5

r6:

h1

 

h2

 

h3: r4

r3 

Resident preferences Hospital preferences 

M = {(r1, h1), (r2, h2), (r3, h3), (r5, h2), (r6, h1)}

(size

5


(r4, h2)

is a blocking pair of

M


HR: blocking pair (3) 

15  

r1: h2

h1

r2: h1

h2

                 

Each hospital has capacity

2

r3: h1

h3

r4: h2 h3

 

h1:

 

r1

 

r3 r2 r5

r6

r5:

h2

 

h1

 

h2:

 

r2

 

r6 r1 r4

r5

r6:

h1

 

h2

 

h3: r4

r3 

Resident preferences Hospital preferences 

M = {(r1, h1), (r2, h2), (r3, h3), (r5, h2), (r6, h1)}

(size

5


(r4, h3)

is a blocking pair of

M


HR: stable matching 

16  

r1:

h2

h1

r2:

h1

h2

                 

Each hospital has capacity

2

r3:

h1

h3

r4: h2

h3

 

h1: r1

r3 r2

r5 r6

r5: h2 h1

 

h2: r2

r6 r1

r4 r5

r6: h1

h2

 

h3:

r4

  r3 

Resident preferences Hospital preferences 

M = {(r1, h2), (r2, h1), (r3, h1), (r4, h3), (r6, h2)}

(size

5


r5

is unmatched

h3

 is undersubscribed


HR: classical results 

17  

      • A stable matching always exists and can be found in linear time [Gale and Shapley, 1962; Gusfield and Irving, 1989]
      • There are resident-optimal and hospital-optimal stable matchings
      • Stable matchings form a distributive lattice [Conway, 1976; Gusfield and Irving, 1989]
      • “Rural Hospitals Theorem”: for a given instance of HR:
        1. the same residents are assigned in all stable matchings;
        2. each hospital is assigned the same number of residents in all stable matchings;
        3. any hospital that is undersubscribed in one stable matching is assigned exactly the same set of residents in all stable matchings.
        • [Roth, 1984; Gale and Sotomayor, 1985; Roth, 1986]

Resident-oriented Gale-Shapley algorithm 

18  

M =

;

while

(some resident ri is unmatched and has a non-empty list)

{  ri applies to the first hospital hj on his list;

   M = M

{(ri,hj)};

  

if

(hj is over-subscribed)

   {  rk = worst resident assigned to hj;

      M = M \ {(rk,hj)};

   }

  

if

(hj is full)

   {  rk = worst resident assigned to hj;

     

for

(each successor rl of rk on hj

s list)

      {  delete rl from hj

s list;

         delete hj from rl

s list;

      }

    

}

}


RGS algorithm: example 

19  

r1: h2 h1

r2: h1 h2

                 

Each hospital has capacity

2

r3: h1 h3

r4: h2 h3

 

h1: r1 r3 r2 r5 r6

r5: h2 h1

 

h2: r2 r6 r1 r4 r5

r6: h1 h2

 

h3: r4 r3 

Resident preferences Hospital preferences


RGS algorithm: example 

20  

r1: h2 h1

r2: h1 h2

                 

Each hospital has capacity

2

r3: h1 h3

r4: h2 h3

 

h1: r1 r3 r2 r5 r6

r5: h2 h1

 

h2: r2 r6 r1 r4 r5

r6: h1 h2

 

h3: r4 r3 

Resident preferences Hospital preferences 

Stable matching:

M = {(r1, h2), (r2, h1), (r3, h1), (r4, h3), (r6, h2)}


Tutorial Outline 

21  

1.1: Classical Hospitals / Residents problem 

1.2: Hospitals / Residents problem with Ties 

1.3: Hospitals / Residents problem with Couples 

1.4: “Almost stable” matchings 

1.5: Social Stability


Hospitals / Residents problem with Ties 

22  

      • In practice, residents’ preference lists are short
      • Hospitals’ lists are generally long, so ties may be used – Hospitals / Residents problem with Ties (HRT)
      • A hospital may be indifferent among several residents
      • E.g., h1: (r1 r3) r2 (r5 r6 r8)
      • Matching M is stable if there is no pair (r,h) such that:

1.

r

,

h

find each other acceptable

2. either

 

r

is unmatched in

M

      

or

r

prefers

h

to his/her assigned hospital in

M

3. either

h

is undersubscribed in

M

      

or

 

h

prefers

r

to its worst resident assigned in

M

      • A matching M is stable in an HRT instance I if and only if M is stable in some instance I of HR obtained from I by breaking the ties [M et al, 1999]

HRT: stable matching (1) 

23  

r1: h1 h2

r2: h1 h2

                 

Each hospital has capacity

2

r3: h1 h3

r4: h2 h3

 

h1: r1 r2 r3 r5 r6

r5: h2 h1

 

h2: r2 r1 r6(r4 r5)

r6: h1 h2

 

h3: r4 r3 

Resident preferences Hospital preferences


HRT: stable matching (1) 

24  

r1:

h1

h2

r2:

h1

h2

                 

Each hospital has capacity

2

r3: h1

h3

r4:

h2

h3

 

h1:

r1

 

r2

r3

 

r5 r6

r5: h2 h1

 

h2: r2 r1

  r6

(

r4

  r5)

r6: h1

h2

 

h3: r4

r3 

Resident preferences Hospital preferences 

M = {(r1, h1), (r2, h1), (r3, h3), (r4, h2), (r6, h2)}

(size

5

)


HRT: stable matching (2) 

25  

r1:

h1

h2

r2:

h1

h2

                 

Each hospital has capacity

2

r3: h1

h3

r4: h2

h3

 

h1:

r1

 

r2

r3

 

r5 r6

r5:

h2

h1

 

h2: r2 r1

  r6

(r4

r5

)

r6: h1

h2

 

h3:

r4

 

r3 

Resident preferences Hospital preferences 

M = {(r1, h1), (r2, h1), (r3, h3), (r4, h3), (r5, h2), (r6, h2)}

(size

6

)


Maximum stable matchings 

26  

      • Stable matchings can have different sizes
      • A maximum stable matching can be (at most) twice the size of a minimum stable matching
      • Problem of finding a maximum stable matching (MAX HRT) is NP-hard [Iwama, M et al, 1999], even if (simultaneously):
        • each hospital has capacity 1 (Stable Marriage problem with Ties and Incomplete Lists)
        • the ties occur on one side only
        • each preference list is either strictly ordered or is a single tie
        • and
          • either each tie is of length 2 [M et al, 2002]
          • or each preference list is of length 3 [Irving, M, O’Malley, 2009]
      • Minimisation problem is NP-hard too, for similar restrictions!    [M et al, 2002] 

Master lists 

27  

      • In practice there may be a common ranking of residents according to some objective criteria (e.g., academic ability) – a master list
      • Each hospital’s preference list is then derived from this master list
      • Depending on how fine-grained the scoring system is, ties may arise as a result of residents having equal scores
      • MAX HRT is NP-hard even if (simultaneously):
        • each hospital’s preference list is derived from a master list of residents
        • each resident’s preference list is derived from a master list of hospitals
        • each hospital has capacity 1
        • and
          • either there is only a single tie that occurs in one of the master lists
          • or the ties occur in one master list only and are of length 2

[Irving, M and Scott, 2008]


MAX HRT: approximability 

28  

      • MAX HRT is not approximable within 33/29 unless P=NP, even if each hospital has capacity 1 [Yanagisawa, 2007]
      • MAX HRT is not approximable within 4/3- assuming the Unique Games Conjecture (UGC) [Yanagisawa, 2007]
      • Trivial 2-approximation algorithm for MAX HRT
      • Succession of papers gave improvements, culminating in:
      • MAX HRT is approximable within 3/2 [McDermid, 2009; Kir��ly, 2012; Paluch 2012]
      • Experimental comparison of approximation algorithms and heuristics for MAX HRT [Irving and M, 2009]

Integer Programming for MAX HRT 

29  

      • Model developed by Augustine Kwanashie (2012)
      • Solved using CPLEX IP solver
      • IP models of HRT instances with tie density of about 85% are the most likely to be computationally hard
      • Figure below shows median computation times for increasing sizes of 10 HRT instances each with 85% tie density (all preference lists of length 5)
      • Real world SFAS datasets were also solved using the IP model. 
         
         
         
         
         

Tutorial Outline 

30  

1.1: Classical Hospitals / Residents problem 

1.2: Hospitals / Residents problem with Ties 

1.3: Hospitals / Residents problem with Couples 

1.4: “Almost stable” matchings 

1.5: Social Stability


Couples in HR 

31  

      • Pairs of residents who wish to be matched to geographically close hospitals form couples
      • Each couple (ri,rj) ranks in order of preference a set of pairs of hospitals (hp,hq) representing the assignment of ri to hp and rj to hq
      • Stability definition may be extended to this case [Roth, 1984; McDermid and M, 2010; Bir�� et al, 2011]
      • Gives the Hospitals / Residents problem with Couples (HRC)
      • A stable matching need not exist:

      (r1,r2): (h1,h2)  h1:1: r1 r3 r2

          r3:

(

h1 h2  h2:1: r1 r3 r2 

 


Couples in HR 

32  

      • Pairs of residents who wish to be matched to geographically close hospitals form couples
      • Each couple (ri,rj) ranks in order of preference a set of pairs of hospitals (hp,hq) representing the assignment of ri to hp and rj to hq
      • Stability definition may be extended to this case [Roth, 1984; McDermid and M, 2010; Bir�� et al, 2011]
      • Gives the Hospitals / Residents problem with Couples (HRC)
      • A stable matching need not exist:

      (r1,r2): (h1,h2)  h1:1: r1 r3 r2

          r3:

(

h1 h2  h2:1: r1 r3 r2 

      • Stable matchings can have different sizes

 


Couples in HR 

33  

      • Pairs of residents who wish to be matched to geographically close hospitals form couples
      • Each couple (ri,rj) ranks in order of preference a set of pairs of hospitals (hp,hq) representing the assignment of ri to hp and rj to hq
      • Stability definition may be extended to this case [Roth, 1984; McDermid and M, 2010; Bir�� et al, 2011]
      • Gives the Hospitals / Residents problem with Couples (HRC)
      • A stable matching need not exist:

      (r1,r2): (h1,h2)  h1:1: r1 r3 r2

          r3:

(

h1 h2  h2:1: r1 r3 r2 

      • Stable matchings can have different sizes

 


Couples in HR 

34  

      • The problem of determining whether a stable matching exists in a given HRC instance is NP-complete, even if each hospital has capacity 1 and:
        • there are no single residents 

    [Ng and Hirschberg, 1988; Ronn, 1990] 

        • there are no single residents, and
        • each couple has a preference list of length ≤2, and
        • each hospital has a preference list of length ≤3

    [M and McBride, 2013] 

        • the preference list of each single resident, couple and hospital is derived from a strictly ordered master list of hospitals, pairs of hospitals and residents respectively [Bir�� et al, 2011], and
        • each preference list is of length ≤3, and
        • the instance forms a “dual market” 
          [M and McBride, 2013]
 
 
 

 


Algorithm for HRC 

35  

      • Algorithm C described in [Bir�� et al, 2011]:
      • A Gale-Shapley like heuristic
      • An agent is a single resident or a couple
      • Agents apply to entries on their preference lists
      • When a member of an assigned couple is rejected their partner must withdraw from their assigned hospital
      • This creates a vacancy – so any resident previously rejected by the hospital in question may have to be reconsidered
      • The algorithm need not terminate
        • if it terminates, the matching found is guaranteed to be stable
        • it cannot terminate if there is no stable matching
        • it need not terminate even if there is a stable matching

Algorithm C: example 

36  

Resident preferences

    r:  h1 h5

    r:  h6 h8

(r1,r5) : (h1,h2) (h3,h6)

(r2,r4) : (h4,h5) (h1,h2) (h3,h7)

(r6,r8) : (h6,h8) 

Hospital preferences derived from the following master list:

r1 r2 r3 r4 r5 r6 r7 r8 

Each hospital has capacity

1 

cycle


Stable matching 

37  

Resident preferences

    r:  h1 h5

    r:  h6 h8

(r1,r5) : (h1,h2) (h3,h6)

(r2,r4) : (h4,h5) (h1,h2) (h3,h7)

(r6,r8) : (h6,h8) 

Hospital preferences

r1 r2 r3 r4 r5 r6 r7 r8 

Each hospital has capacity

1 

Stable matching:

M = {(r1, h3), (r2, h1), (r3, h5), (r4, h2), (r5, h6), (r7, h8)}


Empirical evaluation 

38  

      • Extensive empirical evaluation due to [Bir�� et al, 2011]:
      • Compared 5 variants of Algorithm C against 10 other algorithms
      • Instances generated with varying:
        • sizes
        • numbers of couples
        • densities of the “compatibility matrix”
        • lengths of time given to each instance
      • Measured proportion of instances found to admit a stable matching
      • Clear conclusion:
        • high likelihood of finding a stable matching (with Algorithm C) if the number / proportion of couples is low

Integer Programming for HRC 

39  

      • Model developed by Iain McBride (2013)
      • Solved using CPLEX IP solver
      • Random instances, scalability (preference lists of length between 5 and 10):
        • 5000 residents, 500 hospitals, 500 couples, 5000 posts (x25)
          • solved in 99.6 seconds on average
        • 10000 residents, 1000 hospitals, 1000 couples, 10000 posts (x1)
          • solved in 10 minutes
      • Random instances, solvability / sizes of  
        largest stable matchings found:
        • 500 residents, 50 hospitals, 250  
          couples, 500 posts (x1000)
          • around 70% of instances were solvable
          • Average time taken 75s per instance
      • SFAS instances:
        • 2012: 710 residents, stable matching of size 681 found in 16s
        • 2011: 736 residents, stable matching of size 688 found in 17s
        • 2010: 734 residents, stable matching of size 681 found in 65s

Scottish Foundation Allocation Scheme 

40  

      • Set of applicants and programmes (residents and  
        hospitals)
      • Up to 2012: each applicant
        • ranks 10 programmes in strict order of preference
        • has a score in the range 40..100
      • Two applicants can link their applications
        • preferences are interleaved in a precise way to form their joint preference list
        • only compatible programmes appear on joint preference list
      • Each programme
        • has a capacity indicating the number of posts it has
        • has a preference list derived from the above scoring function
          • so ties are possible

The outcome 

41  

      • Round 1
        • 710 applicants
        • 52 programmes with a total of 720 posts
        • 17 linked pairs
        • Stable matching found
        • Solution found matched 683 applicants, including all linked pairs
      • Round 2 
        • 27 applicants
        • 37 posts remaining at 10 programmes
        • No linked pairs
        • Applicants ranked all remaining programmes
        • Stable matching found
        • Solution found matched all remaining applicants

Tutorial Outline 

42  

1.1: Classical Hospitals / Residents problem 

1.2: Hospitals / Residents problem with Ties 

1.3: Hospitals / Residents problem with Couples 

1.4: “Almost stable” matchings 

1.5: Social Stability


Maximum matchings vs stable matchings 

      • Maximum matchings can be twice the size of stable matchings
      • Example (each hospital has capacity 1): 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 

r1: h1 h2     h1: r1 r2

r2: h1

2

      h2: r1


Maximum matchings vs stable matchings 

44  

      • Maximum matchings can be twice the size of stable matchings
      • Example (each hospital has capacity 1): 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 

r1: h1 h2     h1: r1 r2

r2: h1

  1

     h2: r1 

r1 

r2 

h1 

h2 

r1: h1 h2     h1: r1 r2

r2: h1

2

      h2: r1 

r1 

r2 

h1 

h2 

 

stable matching  

maximum matching


Maximum matchings vs stable matchings 

      • A small number of blocking pairs could be tolerated if it is possible to find a larger matching
      • But, different maximum matchings can have different numbers of blocking pairs 
      • Example: 
        (each hospital  
        has capacity 1
      • Every stable matching has size 3 
 
 
 

r1: h4 h1 h3       h1: r4 r1 r2

r2: h2 h1 h4       h2: r3 r2 r4

r3: h2 h4 h3       h3: r1 r3

r4: h1 h4 h2       h4: r4 r1 r3 r2


Maximum matchings vs stable matchings 

      • A small number of blocking pairs could be tolerated if it is possible to find a larger matching
      • But, different maximum matchings can have different numbers of blocking pairs 
      • Example: 
        (each hospital  
        has capacity 1
      • Maximum matching M1={(r1,h1), (r2,h2), (r3,h3), (r4,h4)} 
      • Blocking pairs of M1: (r3,h2), (r4,h1)   (2) 
 

r1: h4 h1 h3       h1: r4 r1 r2

r2: h2 h1 h4       h2: r3 r2 r4

r3: h2 h4 h3       h3: r1 r3

r4: h1 h4 h2       h4: r4 r1 r3 r2


Maximum matchings vs stable matchings 

      • A small number of blocking pairs could be tolerated if it is possible to find a larger matching
      • But, different maximum matchings can have different numbers of blocking pairs 
      • Example: 
        (each hospital  
        has capacity 1
      • Maximum matching M2={(r1,h1), (r2,h4), (r3,h3), (r4,h2)} 
      • Blocking pairs of M2: (r1,h4), (r2,h2), (r3,h2), (r3,h4), (r4,h1), (r4,h4)   (6) 
 

r1: h4 h1 h3       h1: r4 r1 r2

r2: h2 h1 h4       h2: r3 r2 r4

r3: h2 h4 h3       h3: r1 r3

r4: h1 h4 h2       h4: r4 r1 r3 r2


Maximum matchings vs stable matchings 

      • A small number of blocking pairs could be tolerated if it is possible to find a larger matching
      • But, different maximum matchings can have different numbers of blocking pairs 
      • Example: 
        (each hospital  
        has capacity 1
      • Maximum matching M3={(r1,h4), (r2,h2), (r3,h3), (r4,h1)} 
      • Blocking pairs of M3: (r3,h2)    (1) 
 

r1: h4 h1 h3       h1: r4 r1 r2

r2: h2 h1 h4       h2: r3 r2 r4

r3: h2 h4 h3       h3: r1 r3

r4: h1 h4 h2       h4: r4 r1 r3 r2


“Almost stable” matchings 

      • Given an instance of HR, the problem is to find a maximum matching that is “almost stable”, i.e., admits the minimum number of blocking pairs
      • The problem is: 
        • NP-hard
          • even if every preference list is of length 3
        • not approximable within n1-, for any > 0, unless P=NP, where n is the number of residents
        • solvable in polynomial time if each resident’s list is of length 2
      • In all cases the result is true if each hospital has capacity 1 
      • [Biro, M and Mittal, 2010] 

Tutorial Outline 

50  

1.1: Classical Hospitals / Residents problem 

1.2: Hospitals / Residents problem with Ties 

1.3: Hospitals / Residents problem with Couples 

1.4: “Almost stable” matchings 

1.5: Social Stability


The Social Network Graph 

51  

      • A blocking pair (r,h) of a matching M may not necessarily lead to M being undermined in practice
        • Especially if r and h are unaware of each other’s preference list
      • Consider an HR instance I augmented by a social network graph 
        • A bipartite graph comprising a subset of the acceptable resident-hospital pairs that have some social ties
      • A resident-hospital pair is acquainted if  
        they form an edge in the social network  
        graph, and unacquainted otherwise 
      • Unacquainted pairs cannot block a matching 
 

1 

2 

3 

4 

5 

6 

1 

2 

3 

Social network graph

G 

Residents 

Hospitals


Example 

52  

      • Example:
 

r1: h2 h1

r2: h1 h2

                 

Each hospital has capacity

2

r3: h1 h3

r4: h2 h3

 

h1: r1 r3 r2 r5 r6

r5: h2 h1

 

h2: r2 r6 r1 r4 r5

r6: h1 h2

 

h3: r4 r3 

Resident preferences Hospital preferences 

      • Unacquainted pairs: {(r1,h2), (r3,h1), (r5,h2)}
 
 

1 

2 

3 

4 

5 

6 

1 

2 

3 

Social network graph

G 

Residents 

Hospitals


Example 

53  

      • Example:
 

r1:

h2

h1

r2:

h1

h2

                 

Each hospital has capacity

2

r3: h1

h3

r4: h2

h3

 

h1: r1 r3

r2 r5

r6

r5: h2

h1

 

h2: r2

r6 r1

r4 r5

r6: h1

h2

 

h3:

r4 r3 

Resident preferences Hospital preferences 

      • Unacquainted pairs: {(r1,h2), (r3,h1), (r5,h2)}
      • (r3,h1) is no longer allowed to block the matching 
 
 

1 

2 

3 

4 

5 

6 

1 

2 

3 

Social network graph

G 

Residents 

Hospitals


Social stability 

54  

      • A pair (r,h) socially blocks a matching M if:
        • (r,h) blocks M in the classical sense
        • (r,h) is an acquainted pair
      • M is socially stable if it has no social blocking pair 
      • An instance of the Hospitals / Residents problem under Social Stability (HRSS) comprises an HR instance I and a social network graph G 
      • Given an HRSS instance (I,G), any stable matching in I is socially stable in (I,G

Socially stable matchings of different sizes 

55  

      • Example:
 

r1:

h2

h1

r2:

h1

h2

                 

Each hospital has capacity

2

r3: h1

h3

r4: h2

h3

 

h1: r1 r3

r2 r5

r6

r5: h2

h1

 

h2: r2

r6 r1

r4 r5

r6: h1

h2

 

h3:

r4 r3 

Resident preferences Hospital preferences 

      • Socially stable matching of size 6
 
 

1 

2 

3 

4 

5 

6 

1 

2 

3 

Social network graph

G 

Residents 

Hospitals


Socially stable matchings of different sizes 

56  

      • Example:
 

r1:

h2

h1

r2:

h1

h2

                 

Each hospital has capacity

2

r3:

h1

h3

r4: h2

h3

 

h1: r1

r3

 

r2

r5

 

r6

r5: h2 h1

 

h2: r2

r6 r1

r4 r5

r6: h1

h2

 

h3:

r4

r3 

Resident preferences Hospital preferences 

      • Stable matching of size 5
 
 

1 

2 

3 

4 

5 

6 

1 

2 

3 

Social network graph

G 

Residents 

Hospitals


Algorithmic results 

57  

      • The problem of finding a maximum socially stable matching, given an instance of HRSS, is:
        • NP-hard, even if all preference lists are of length 3 and each hospital has capacity 1 
        • solvable in polynomial-time if: 
          • each resident’s list is of length 2, or 
          • the number of acquainted pairs is constant, or 
          • the number of unacquainted pairs is constant 
        • approximable within 3/2 
        • not approximable better than 3/2 assuming the Unique Games Conjecture 
        • [Askalidis, Immorlica, Kwanashie, M and Pountourakis, 2013] 

Open problems 

58  

      • Approximation algorithm for MAX HRT with performance guarantee < 3/2?
        • consider special cases:
          • ties on one side only
          • master lists
      • To cope with the complexity of HRC, try to find a matching that is “as stable as possible” 
        • one possibility: find a matching with the minimum number of blocking pairs
          • problem is NP-hard
          • approximability is open
      • Acknowledgement: thanks to Iain McBride and Augustine Kwanashie 

Further reading 

59  

      • Chapters 3, 5

References 

60  

Abraham, D.J., Blum, A. and Sandholm, T. (2007). Clearing algorithms for barter exchange markets: enabling nationwide kidney exchanges, in Proceedings of EC ’07: the 8th ACM Conference on Electronic Commerce (ACM), pp. 295–304

 

Abraham, D.J., Cechl��rov��, K., Manlove, D.F. and Mehlhorn, K. (2004). Pareto optimality in house allocation problems, in Proceedings of ISAAC ’04: the 15th Annual International Symposium on Algorithms and Computation, Lecture Notes in Computer Science, Vol. 3341 (Springer), pp. 3–15

 

Abraham, D.J., Chen, N., Kumar, V. and Mirrokni, V.S. (2006). Assignment problems in rental markets, in Proceedings of WINE ’06: the 2nd International Workshop on Internet and Network Economics, Lecture Notes in Computer Science, Vol. 4286 (Springer), pp. 198–213 

Abraham, D.J., Irving, R.W., Kavitha, T. and Mehlhorn, K. (2005). Popular matchings, in Proceedings of SODA ’05: the 16th ACM-SIAM Symposium on Discrete Algorithms (ACM-SIAM), pp. 424–432 

Ashlagi, I., Fischer, F., Kash, I. and Procaccia, A. D. (2010). Mix and match, in Proceedings of EC ’10: the 11th ACM Conference on Electronic Commerce (ACM), pp. 305–314


References 

61  

Ashlagi, I. and Roth, A. (2011). Individual rationality and participation in large scale, multi-hospital kidney exchange, in Proceedings of EC ’11: the 12th ACM Conference on Electronic Commerce (ACM), pp. 321–322 

Ashlagi, I. and Roth, A. (2012). New challenges in multihospital kidney exchange, American Economic Review 102, 3, pp. 354–359 

Askalidis, G., Immorlica, I., Kwanashie, A., Manlove, D.F., Pountourakis, E. (2013).  Socially Stable matchings in the Hospitals / Residents problem.  To appear in Proceedings of WADS 2013: the 13th Algorithms and Data Structures Symposium, Lecture Notes in Computer Science, Springer, 2013 

Bir��, P., Irving, R.W. and Schlotter, I. (2011). Stable matching with couples: an empirical study, ACM Journal of Experimental Algorithmics 16, section 1, article 2, 27 pages

 

Bir��, P., Manlove, D.F. and Mittal, S. (2010).  Size versus stability in the Marriage problem.  Theoretical Computer Science 411, pp. 1828-1841 

Bir��, P., Manlove, D.F. and Rizzi, R (2009). Maximum weight cycle packing in directed graphs, with application to kidney exchange, Discrete Mathematics, Algorithms and Applications 1, 4, pp. 499–517


References 

62  

Caragiannis, I., Filos-Ratsikas, A. and Procaccia, A. (2011). An improved 2-agent kidney exchange mechanism, in Proceedings of WINE ’11: the 7th International Workshop on Internet and Network Economics, Lecture Notes in Computer Science Series, vol. 7090 (Springer), pp. 37–48 

Chen, Y. and Sönmez, T. (2002). Improving efficiency of on-campus housing: An experimental study, American Economic Review 92, 5, pp. 1669–1686 

Conway,  J.H. (1976).  Personal communication, reported in Knuth, D.E. (1976). Mariages Stables (Les Presses de L’Universit�� de Montr��al). English translation in Stable Marriage and its Relation to Other Combinatorial Problems, volume 10 of CRM Proceedings and Lecture Notes, American Mathematical Society, 1997 

Dubins, L.E. and Freedman, D.A. (1981). Machiavelli and the Gale-Shapley algorithm, American Mathematical Monthly 88, 7, pp. 485–494 

Gabow, H.N. and Tarjan, R.E. (1989). Faster scaling algorithms for network problems, SIAM Journal on Computing 18, pp. 1013–1036

 

Gale, D. and Shapley, L.S. (1962). College admissions and the stability of marriage, American Mathematical Monthly 69, pp. 9–15


References 

63  

Gale, D. and Sotomayor, M. (1985). Ms. Machiavelli and the stable matching problem, American Mathematical Monthly 92, 4, pp. 261–268

 

Gale, D. and Sotomayor, M. (1985). Some remarks on the stable matching problem, Discrete Applied Mathematics 11, pp. 223–232 

Gärdenfors, P (1975). Match making: assignments based on bilateral preferences,

Behavioural Science 20, pp. 166–173 

Garg, N., Kavitha, T., Kumar, A., Mehlhorn, K. and Mestre, J. (2010). Assigning papers to referees, Algorithmica 58, 1, pp. 119–136 

Glorie, K.M., Klundert, J.J. van de and Wagelmans, A. (2013). Iterative branch-and-price for hierarchical multi-criteria kidney exchange. Econometric Institute Research Paper EI 2012-11, Erasmus University Rotterdam 

Gusfield, D. and Irving, R.W. (1989). The Stable Marriage Problem: Structure and Algorithms (MIT Press) 

Huang, C.-C. (2006). Cheating by men in the Gale-Shapley stable matching algorithm, in Proceedings of ESA ’06: the 14th Annual European Symposium on Algorithms, Lecture Notes in Computer Science, Vol. 4168 (Springer), pp. 418–431


References 

64  

Huang, C.-C. and Kavitha, T. (2012). Weight-maximal matchings, in Proceedings of MATCH-UP ’12: the 2nd International Workshop on Matching Under Preferences, pp. 87–98 

Immorlica, N. and Mahdian, M. (2005). Marriage, honesty and stability, in Proceedings of SODA ’05: the 16th Annual ACM-SIAM Symposium on Discrete Algorithms (ACM-SIAM), pp. 53–62 

Irving, R.W. (1985). An efficient algorithm for the “stable roommates” problem, Journal of Algorithms, 6, pp. 577-595 

Irving, R.W. (2007). Greedy and generous matchings via a variant of the Bellman-Ford algorithm, Unpublished manuscript 

Irving, R.W., Kavitha, T., Mehlhorn, K., Michail, D. and Paluch, K. (2004). Rank-maximal matchings, in Proceedings of SODA ’04: the 15th ACM-SIAM Symposium on Discrete Algorithms (ACM-SIAM), pp. 68–75 

Irving, R.W. and Manlove, D.F. (2009). Finding large stable matchings, ACM Journal of Experimental Algorithmics 14, section 1, article 2, 30 pages


References 

65  

Irving, R.W., Manlove, D.F. and O’Malley, G. (2009). Stable marriage with ties and bounded length preference lists, Journal of Discrete Algorithms 7, 2, pp. 213–219 

Irving, R.W., Manlove, D.F. and Scott, S. (2008). The stable marriage problem with master preference lists, Discrete Applied Mathematics 156, 15, pp. 2959–2977 

Iwama, K., Manlove, D., Miyazaki, S. and Morita, Y. (1999). Stable marriage with incomplete lists and ties, in Proceedings of ICALP ’99: the 26th International Colloquium on Automata, Languages, and Programming, Lecture Notes in Computer Science, Vol. 1644 (Springer), pp. 443–452 

Keizer, K.M. , de Klerk, M., Haase-Kromwijk, B.J.J.M., and Weimar, W. (2005). The Dutch algorithm for allocation in living donor kidney exchange. Transplantation Proceedings, 37, pp. 589–591 

Kir��ly, Z. (2012). Linear time local approximation algorithm for maximum stable marriage, in Proceedings of MATCH-UP ’12: the 2nd International Workshop on Matching Under Preferences, pp. 99–110 

Kobayashi, H. and Matsui, T. (2010). Cheating strategies for the Gale-Shapley algorithm with complete preference lists, Algorithmica 58, 1, pp. 151–169


References 

66  

Manlove, D.F., Irving, R.W., Iwama, K., Miyazaki, S. and Morita, Y. (1999). Hard variants of stable marriage, Tech. Rep. TR-1999-43, University of Glasgow, School of Computing Science 

Manlove, D.F., Irving, R.W., Iwama, K., Miyazaki, S. and Morita, Y. (2002). Hard variants of stable marriage, Theoretical Computer Science 276, 1-2, pp. 261–279

 

Manlove, D.F. and McBride, I. (2013). The Hospitals / Residents problem with Couples, Unpublished manuscript 

Manlove, D.F. and O’Malley, G. (2012). Paired and Altruistic Kidney Donation in the UK. In Proceedings of SEA 2012: the 11th International Symposium on Experimental Algorithms, Lecture Notes in Computer Science, Vol. 7276 (Springer), pp. 271-282 

McDermid, E. (2009). A 3/2 approximation algorithm for general stable marriage, in Proceedings of ICALP ’09: the 36th International Colloquium on Automata, Languages and Programming, Lecture Notes in Computer Science, Vol. 5555 (Springer), pp. 689–700 

McDermid, E.J. and Manlove, D.F. (2010). Keeping partners together: Algorithmic results for the hospitals / residents problem with couples, Journal of Combinatorial Optimization 19, 3, pp. 279–303


References 

67  

Micali, S. and Vazirani, V.V. (1980). An O(

|V |・|E|) algorithm for finding maximum matching in general graphs, in Proceedings of FOCS ’80: the 21st Annual IEEE Symposium on Foundations of Computer Science (IEEE Computer Society), pp. 17–27. 

Ng, C. and Hirschberg, D.S. (1988). Complexity of the stable marriage and stable roommate problems in three dimensions, Tech. Rep. UCI-ICS 88-28, Department of Information and Computer Science, University of California, Irvine 

Paluch, K. (2012). Faster and simpler approximation of stable matchings, in Proceedings of WAOA ’11: 9th Workshop on Approximation and Online Algorithms, Lecture Notes in Computer Science, Vol. 7164 (Springer), pp. 176–187 

Perach, N., Polak, J. and Rothblum, U.G. (2008). A stable matching model with an entrance criterion applied to the assignment of students to dormitories at the Technion, International Journal of Game Theory 36, 3-4, pp. 519–535 

Pini, M.S., Rossi, F., Venable, K.B. and Walsh, T. (2011). Manipulation complexity and gender neutrality in stable marriage procedures, Autonomous Agents and Multi-Agent Systems 22, 1, pp. 183–199 

Rees, M.A., Kopke, J.E., Pelletier, R.P. et al. (2009).  A nonsimultaneous, extended, altruistic-donor chain, New England Journal of Medicine, 360, pp. 1096–1101


References 

68  

Ronn, E. (1990). NP-complete stable matching problems, Journal of Algorithms 11, pp. 285–304 

Roth, A.E. (1982). The economics of matching: Stability and incentives, Mathematics of Operations Research 7, 4, pp. 617–628 

Roth, A.E. (1982a). Incentive compatibility in a market with indivisible goods, Economics Letters 9, pp. 127–132 

Roth, A.E. (1984). The evolution of the labor market for medical interns and residents: a case study in game theory, Journal of Political Economy 92, 6, pp. 991–1016 

Roth, A.E. (1986). On the allocation of residents to rural hospitals: a general property of two-sided matching markets, Econometrica 54, pp. 425–427 

Roth, A.E. and Postlewaite, A. (1977). Weak versus strong domination in a market with indivisible goods, Journal of Mathematical Economics 4, pp. 131–137  

Roth, A.E., Sönmez, T. and Ünver M.U. (2004). Kidney exchange. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119, 2, pp. 457–488


References 

69  

Roth, A.E., Sönmez, T. and Ünver., M.U. (2005). Pairwise kidney exchange. Journal of Economic Theory, 125, pp. 151–188 

Roth, A.E., Sönmez, T. and Ünver., M.U. (2007). Efficient kidney exchange: Coincidence of wants in a market with compatibility-based preferences. American Economic Review, 97, 3, 828–851 

Teo, C.-P., Sethuraman, J. and Tan, W.-P. (1999). Gale-Shapley stable marriage problem revisited: strategic issues and applications, Management Science 47, 9, pp. 1252–1267 

Toulis, P. and Parkes, D. (2011). A random graph model of kidney exchanges: efficiency, individual rationality and incentives, in Proceedings of the 12th ACM conference on Electronic commerce (ACM), pp. 323–332 

Yanagisawa, H. (2007). Approximation Algorithms for Stable Marriage Problems, Ph.D. thesis, Kyoto University, School of Informatics 

Yuan, Y. (1996). Residence exchange wanted: a stable residence exchange problem, European Journal of Operational Research 90, pp. 536–546


Search more related documents:Insert Presentation title here

Set Home | Add to Favorites

All Rights Reserved Powered by Free Document Search and Download

Copyright © 2011
This site does not host pdf,doc,ppt,xls,rtf,txt files all document are the property of their respective owners. complaint#nuokui.com
TOP